How to Strand Assets
Nature-saving through disruptive technological change
by Ted Nordhaus and Michael Shellenberger
In
1849, the wife of an American entrepreneur named Samuel Kier was
prescribed “American Medicinal Oil” — petroleum — by her doctor to treat
an illness. The Iroquois Indians had used petroleum as an insect
repellent, salve, and tonic for hundreds of years. The so-called “rock
oil” that naturally seeped out of the ground was viewed as a blessing,
and for hundreds of years they skimmed it off the surface of rivers and
streams.
With
his wife feeling better, Kier saw a business opportunity. He started
his own brand, “Kier’s Petroleum or Rock Oil,” and sold bottles for 50
cents through a sales force traveling through the region by wagon.
But
Kier was ambitious and sought other uses for his product. A chemist
recommended he distill it, and use it as lighting fluid. Kier’s
contribution to the emerging petroleum revolution was the creation of
the first industrial-scale refinery in downtown Pittsburgh.
Others
saw the opportunity created by Kier. A group of New York investors
hired an itinerant and disabled engineer with good expertise in salt
drilling to poke around in Pennsylvania for petroleum. In 1858, Edwin
Drake drilled and hit a gusher of oil, triggering what would be the
first of many oil-and-gas based land rushes in American history.
Kerosene
rapidly took over the market for lighting fluids in the United States.
At its peak, whaling produced 13 million gallons of whale oil annually.
The petroleum industry achieved that level just two years after Drake’s oil strike in Pennsylvania. Whalers literally quit their jobs and sought work in the oil fields.
Three years after Drake’s oil strike, Vanity Fair ran
a cartoon showing upright sperm whales, dressed in tuxedos and ball
gowns, toasting each other with champagne at a fine celebration. The
caption read, “Grand ball given by the whales to celebrate the discovery
of the oil wells in Pennsylvania.”
Twenty-five
years before Kier began selling his medicinal oil, the great naturalist
and painter John James Audubon wrote in his journal from the deck of
his ship approaching England: “What nakedness the country exhibits, with
scarce a patch of timber to be seen. [America’s] fine forests of pine,
of oak, of heavy walnut trees, of magnificent magnolias, of hickory, or
ash, or sugar trees, are represented here by a diminutive growth named
furze.”
Today
England is verdant, but two centuries after it had begun its transition
from wood to coal, the landscape Audubon described was still barren,
and forests were kept to supply energy, not as places for wildlife and
contemplation.
The
rapid transition from wood to coal in the nineteenth and twentieth
centuries ultimately would allow England’s forests to recover. Coal
stranded the wood fuel industry just as petroleum stranded the whaling
industry. In 1900, just 2 to 3 percent of England was covered by
forests. Today, 10 to 12 percent is.
Looking
back through the lens of our twenty-first-century environmental
consciousness, it can be hard to wrap our heads around it, but coal and
oil, the steam engine and the internal combustion engine, electricity,
roads, and synthetic fertilizer have almost certainly saved more nature
than all the environmental laws ever written.
Coal
replaced wood for fuel. Petroleum replaced whale oil for lighting
before it was in turn displaced by coal-fired electricity. Cars,
tractors, and trolleys replaced horses and mules on the farm and in the
city as our primary source of motive power, sparing an area the size of
California in the United States alone that had been dedicated to growing
feed for draft animals. Tractors and fertilizer, together with roads
and rail lines that allowed food to get to distant markets, allowed
farming to concentrate on the most productive lands, dramatically
improving yields and allowing marginal farmland to return to nature.
Nobody
at the time thought of the forests, the fields, or the whales that were
spared as a result of these world-changing technologies as stranded
assets. But surely they were. Nor was any of the stranding a response to
environmental concerns, though the environmental benefits that resulted
were enormous.
1.
The
introductory materials for this conference, suggest that “the causes of
asset stranding appear to be changing.” Where asset stranding has
historically been driven by disruptive technological change — creative
destruction, as Joseph Schumpeter famously coined it — the hypothesis
presented here is that “environment-related factors are increasingly
stranding assets across a wide range of sectors and geographies and this
trend is accelerating.”
This
claim suggests a much more fundamental shift in the functioning of
market economies around the world than might first appear to be the
case. Recall that Schumpeter’s signal contribution to the economics
canon was his observation that, contra Adam Smith and all the classical
economists who followed, disruptive technological change was not
something exceptional or external to modern economic systems but rather
endemic and endogenous.
The
suggestion that climate change and the political response to it has
fundamentally altered the basic dynamics of asset stranding suggests
both a return to the earlier classical view of technological change and
asset stranding as exogenous to the normal functioning of market
economies.
Against
this notion, let us suggest that any wholesale stranding of fossil
energy assets in the coming decades will likely happen in the
old-fashioned, Schumpeterian way. By this we mean that large scale asset
stranding in the global energy context will remain, as it has always
been, primarily driven by technological change. Whether from wood to
coal in the nineteenth century or, as is currently underway in the
United States, from coal to gas in the twenty-first, the primary driver
of wholesale transitions to new sources of energy has been that the new
source of energy was not only cleaner but cheaper and more useful.
This
will remain all the more the case in a world in which most people still
need to consume more energy, not less, in order to achieve modern
living standards. Two thirds or more of global emissions in this century
will come from developing economies for the simple reason that fossil
energy remains the most reliable way, arguably the only way, to move
large global populations out of subsistence poverty and into the modern
economy. A wholesale transition away from fossil energy will require low
carbon energy technologies capable of meeting this demand.
Energy
transitions of this nature have, of course, always had a political
context. New technologies often require new rules, institutions, and
infrastructure to take hold. The diffusion of coal and the steam engine
required railways, which in turn required rights of way, concessions,
and new laws to advance. Municipal trolleys and public lighting, much
more than wealthy private individuals purchasing Thomas Edison’s new
fangled light bulbs, were the critical end uses that drove early
electrification. The creation of regulated monopoly utilities similarly
provided the economic and institutional setting for the broad diffusion
of electricity.
But
we should never forget that it is the underlying technological
capabilities that ultimately make the transition possible. Railways
offered a vastly more efficient way to move people and materials over
long distances. Electric lighting made it possible to safely light
outdoor spaces and allowed factories and other enterprises to operate
longer hours. Electric motors brought mechanical power to the city,
liberating industry from needing to be in close proximity to waterways
with good hydraulic resources. Coal and oil were thermally and spatially
far superior to wood and biofuels as primary energy sources.
And
indeed, the best contemporary case we have for the stranding of fossil
energy assets on a large scale follows the old Schumpeterian model
closely. Since 2007, coal-fired generation in the United States has
declined from over 50 percent of total generation to less than 40
percent. It is not the case, as some have claimed, that this has simply
led to the increased export of coal to other locales. During that
period, coal mines have closed and overall coal production has declined
significantly, while coal exports have only risen slightly.
The
largest single factor in that development has been the revolution in
hydraulic fracturing technologies. Natural gas in the United States,
once scarce and costly, is today cheap and abundant. Slow economic
growth and improving energy efficiency have contributed as well. But
while those dynamics have affected clean and dirty sources of energy
alike, the growth of natural gas generation during this period has
almost exclusively displaced coal generation.
That’s
not just because natural gas is cheaper and cleaner. It also requires
significantly lower up-front investment in capital than new coal,
nuclear, solar, or wind per kilowatt of energy generated, and it is
flexible, able to displace both baseload and peaking power stations and
ramp up and down rapidly to back up highly variable wind and solar
energy generation.
Yet
there is more to this story than a driven, independent entrepreneur, in
this case the legendary oil man George Mitchell, changing the world.
Less well known than his early valorization of the visionary
entrepreneur remaking entire industries by inventing disruptive
technologies is the fact that by the early 1920s, Schumpeter had become
convinced that the age of the lone entrepreneur was over.
With
rising technological complexity and scientific specialization, the
corporate research lab had replaced the lone inventor as the primary
site of technological innovation. Schumpeter was skeptical that
corporate managers could bring the same entrepreneurial vision to
innovation that had characterized the earlier generation of inventors.
What
Schumpeter failed to account for was the increasing importance of the
state as a critical driver of mission-driven technological innovation.
From jet engines to microchips and the internet to nuclear reactors and
solar panels, the unmistakable hand of government has been present in
virtually every major technological revolution of the last century.
The
shale revolution was no exception. George Mitchell was the first to
prove that shale gas could be profitably extracted from the Barnett
Shale in West Texas. But that breakthrough was years in the making and
was made possible by decades of public research, development, and
demonstration programs, hands-on field support, and a longstanding
production tax credit.
The
diffusion of hydraulic fracturing has also proceeded in a virtuous
cycle with environmental policy making and activism. As the cost of
shuttering coal plants declined precipitously, stronger air quality
regulations and ultimately the Clean Power Plan became feasible
politically while local policy-makers on public utility commissions and
elsewhere could shut down their coal fleets without overly burdening
ratepayers.
This,
we would posit, is what any large-scale stranding of fossil energy
assets will likely look like — better, cheaper, and cleaner energy
technologies will put the wind at the backs of environmental
policy-makers, who will in turn enact policies that further accelerate
the transition to those technologies.
2.
The
substitutions of kerosene for whale oil and coal for wood are
frequently thought to be stories of scarcity. “The cost of whale oil
rose as the whale population was depleted,” wrote one prominent
environmental economist. “Ships had to go further and stay out longer to
get their quota. The price rose, only the rich were willing to pay for
this luxury good, and so the number of ships declined.”
But
the truth is that whale oil scarcity in the nineteenth Century no more
gave rise to the kerosene industry than a shortage of Nokia cell phones
led Apple to invent the iPhone. Most people never used whale oil to
light their homes. It was always a luxury product. By the time kerosene
was discovered, there were a number of alternative lighting fuels
already in wide use.
By
1860, the markets for both coal gas and lard oil were both larger than
the market for whale oil. As early as 1842, a full 17 years before Drake
hit oil, the New York Journal of Commerce declared, “the hogs have fairly run the whales out of the market.”
Similarly,
it was rising demand for heat, light, and power, driven in large part
by new end-uses of energy in the early phases of the industrial
revolution, not a scarcity of wood, that drove Britain’s transition from
wood to coal.
In
Britain, coal substituted for heating in the 1600s, then for charcoal
used in ironworks in the 1700s. But what really led to the expansion of
coal use was the invention of the steam engine, which became the modern
era’s first general-purpose technology powering trains, ships and
factories.
Misunderstanding
these transitions as primarily stories of scarcity has led many to
believe that making nature-destroying technologies scarce — or more
expensive — should be the highest goal of environmental policy. It has
become accepted wisdom in many quarters of the environmental movement
that, properly valued, the services that nature provides us and the
costs (or externalities) that environmental degradation imposes ought to
be sufficient to justify the preservation of the natural world and
elimination of environmental pollutants.
And
while there are some cases where explicit valuations of the benefits of
nature and the costs of pollution have brought significant
environmental improvements, the primary way that we have saved nature
and improved environmental health over the last two hundred years has
been by rendering land, natural resources, and polluting technologies
worthless. Nature made economically useless is nature saved, and
polluting assets rendered economically superfluous are assets stranded.
There
are two processes through which we strand environmental assets. The
first is substitution. Kerosene substituted for whale oil and reduced
the hunting of whales. Livestock substituted for bushmeat and reduced
the hunting of wild animals. Synthetic rubber substituted for natural
rubber, reducing pressure to convert tropical forests to rubber
plantations.
The
second process is intensification. Fertilizer, irrigation, tractors,
pesticides, and plant breeding have allowed us to grow more food on less
land. Mining energy rather than growing it has allowed us to free up
vast areas of land that was once needed to produce wood and charcoal for
heating and cooking and to feed animals that provided motive power.
Substitution
and intensification, in other words, have been the primary drivers of
environmental asset stranding over time. Most people around the world no
longer depend on bushmeat for protein or firewood for heating and
cooking.
Even
wild catch from the world’s fisheries appears to have peaked, replaced
increasingly by aquaculture, which for the first time in 2014 surpassed
wild fisheries in total production.
Global
farmland too, by some calculations, may be close to its peak, as rising
agricultural productivity has managed for many decades now to keep up
with, and in many places surpass, rising food demand.
Substitution
and intensification also reduce the opportunity costs associated with
conservation and environmental regulation. Kerosene may have saved the
whales in the nineteenth century, but whaling came back with a vengeance
in the twentieth, as better technologies allowed whalers to crisscross
the globe in search of whales and kill them with ruthless efficiency.
Yet
by the time the first effective international limits were established
in the 1970s, most products derived from whales, including meat,
margarine, and lubricants, had been replaced by substitutes, and most
major whaling nations had already abandoned whaling for economic, not
environmental reasons. As a result, the opportunity costs associated
with banning whaling were extremely low.
To
take another well-known example, New York City famously began to
purchase land in the Catskills watershed in the late 1990s to protect
its drinking water quality. This case has been widely promoted as a
textbook example of saving nature by valuing its services. When the cost
of treating New York City’s water is factored into the value of
undeveloped land upstate, it makes good sense to preserve those lands
for water filtration.
But
what really saved the Catskills watershed was agricultural
intensification in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. As
agricultural yields and better transportation links were established to
more-productive farmland in the American Midwest, farmland and dairies
across the Catskills region were abandoned. The Catskills Forest
Preserve, which constitutes about a third of the watershed, was created
in the early twentieth century because the land in the region had lost
so much value that landowners ceased paying property taxes on their
land. The land became delinquent and reverted to public ownership.
While
it is comforting to know that the lands that New York City has
purchased more recently are now publicly owned and protected in
perpetuity, the land was not actually threatened with development. The
City’s land purchase program, in fact, forbade the city from purchasing
land for which there was any other bidder. As a result, the average cost
of purchase was roughly one hundred times less than the cost of
purchasing land in surrounding areas where there was an active market.
Once again, we see that what made it possible to formally strand these
assets was that the opportunity costs associated with protecting them
were already extremely low.
Finally,
consider the global effort to eliminate chlorofluorocarbons. The world
struggled for the better part of a decade to enact a phaseout of
ozone-depleting chemicals. Policies were established in some places,
mostly wealthy developed nations, to phase out some uses of CFCs. But
lacking a cheap and widely available substitute for critical uses in
refrigeration and air conditioning, a global phaseout remained beyond
reach. It was not until DuPont demonstrated the ability to produce a
cheap substitute at industrial scales that a global phaseout became
possible, and within a few years of the announcement that DuPont had
done so, a global agreement was in place.
If
there is a lesson here, it is that large-scale stranding of assets will
not occur by political fiat. The availability of cheap, scalable
substitutes will be the precondition to any such future. Carbon pricing,
emissions caps, divestment, and all similar asset-stranding strategies
will be dependent upon the development of cheap, widely available
substitutes.
Low
carbon technologies have to date failed to offer a real alternative to
fossil energy at scales that would have much impact on climate change.
For this reason, decades of efforts to cap emissions internationally and
reduce global dependence on fossil fuels have failed to have any impact
on global emissions.
If
there is reason for optimism, it is that it is not scarcity, but
humankind’s quest for more heat, light, and power that has been the main
driver of invention and innovation.
We
in the rich world have for too long viewed rising consumption as a mere
threat and not an opportunity. We have thus sought in a variety of ways
to make energy more scarce. But the history of energy transitions and
techno-economic paradigms shows that we can take advantage of rising
demand to create new substitutes.
And
to a great extent, that’s what’s happening. Whether solar or nuclear
energy, we are seeing China, the US, and Europe working together to make
cleaner sources of energy cheap — not through pricing carbon but by
directly investing in those technologies. Just this week we’ve seen Bill
Gates announce a project to work with the Chinese government to develop
a next-generation nuclear reactor that not only can’t melt down but
also recycles waste as fuel. And we have seen three prominent
pro-nuclear green activists in Britain call for the UK to abandon its
last-generation Hinkley nuclear plant and instead build a
next-generation nuclear one.
What’s
motivating Bill Gates and pro-nuclear activists here is the same goal:
making nuclear cheaper than fossil fuels so it can diffuse around the
world and strand fossil fuel assets. These steps mark a new phase in the
effort to stabilize carbon emissions. While there remains talk and
hopes of a global carbon price, the reality is that we will leave fossil
fuels in the ground for the same reason that we left whales in the
ocean: because we no longer need them.
____________
Michael Shellenberger, President, Breakthrough Institute
436 14th St, Suite 820 :: Oakland, CA 94612 :: cell (best): 415-309-4200 :: office: 510.550.8800 x355 :: Skype: Shellenberger
No comments:
Post a Comment